International Grain Reserves : And Other Instruments to Address Volatility in Grain Markets

In the long view, recent grain price volatility is not anomalous. Wheat, rice, and maize are highly substitutable in the global market for calories, and when aggregate stocks decline to minimal feasible levels, prices become highly sensitive to small shocks, consistent with storage models. In this decade, stocks have declined due to high income growth and biofuels mandates. Recently, shocks including the Australian drought and biofuels demand boosts due to the oil price spike were exacerbated by a sequence of trade restrictions by key exporters beginning in the thin global rice market in the fall of 2007, which turned market anxiety into panic. To protect vulnerable consumers, countries intervened in storage markets and, if they were exporters, to limit trade access. Recognizing these realities, vulnerable countries are building strategic reserves. The associated expense and negative incentive effects can be controlled if reserves have quantitative targets related to the consumption needs of the most vulnerable, with distribution to the latter only in severe emergencies. More-ambitious plans manipulate world prices via buffer stocks or naked short speculation to keep prices consistent with fundamentals. Past interventions of either kind have been expensive, ineffective, and generally short-lived. Further, there is no significant evidence that prices do not reflect fundamentals, including export market access.

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Main Author: Wright, Brian
Language:English
Published: 2009-08-01
Subjects:ACCOUNTING, ACCUMULATION OF DEBT, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AGRICULTURAL COMMODITIES, AGRICULTURAL COMMODITY, AGRICULTURE, ARBITRAGE, AVERAGE PRICE, BEHAVIOR OF PRICES, BID, CALL OPTION, CAPITALIST ECONOMIES, CARTEL, CASH INFLOW, COMMODITIES, COMMODITY, COMMODITY PRICE, COMMODITY PRICES, COMPETITIVE MARKET, CONSUMERS, CONSUMPTION INCREASES, CONSUMPTION LEVELS, CORN PRICE, COST INCREASES, COST OF CAPITAL, DEBT, DEMAND CURVE, DEMAND GROWTH, DEPOSITS, DEVELOPING COUNTRIES, DEVELOPMENT ECONOMICS, DOMESTIC MARKET, DOMESTIC PRICE, DOMESTIC PRICES, DUMPING, ECONOMIC ORDER, ECONOMICS RESEARCH, EMERGING ECONOMIES, ENERGY PRICE, ENERGY PRICES, EXCHANGE RATE, EXCHANGE RATE MOVEMENTS, EXISTING GOVERNMENT, EXPECTED RETURNS, EXPECTED VALUE, EXPENDITURE, EXPENDITURES, EXPORT MARKET, EXPORTER, EXPORTERS, EXPORTS, FINANCIAL FLOWS, FINANCIAL MARKETS, FINANCIAL SECTOR, FIXED INTEREST, FIXED INTEREST RATE, FLOOR PRICE, FLOOR PRICES, FOOD PRICE, FOOD PRICES, FORECASTS, FREE MARKET, FUND INVESTMENT, FUTURES, FUTURES CONTRACTS, FUTURES MARKET, FUTURES MARKETS, GLOBAL CAPITAL, GLOBAL MARKET, GLOBAL MARKETS, GLOBALIZATION, GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE, GOVERNMENT FUNDS, GOVERNMENT REVENUE, HEDGE FUNDS, HEDGES, HOLDING, HOLDINGS, HOUSING MARKET, HUMAN CAPITAL, INCENTIVE EFFECTS, INCOME, INCOME GROWTH, INCOMES, INFLATION, INSURANCE, INTEREST COSTS, INTEREST RATE, INTEREST RATE POLICIES, INTEREST RATES, INTERNATIONAL BANK, INTERNATIONAL COOPERATION, INTERNATIONAL DEBATES, INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY, INTERNATIONAL FINANCE, INTERNATIONAL MARKET, INTERNATIONAL MARKETS, INTERNATIONAL RESERVES, INTERNATIONAL TRADE, INVESTMENT BEHAVIOR, INVESTMENT VEHICLES, LIQUIDITY, MARGINAL COST, MARGINAL VALUE, MARKET ACCESS, MARKET BEHAVIOR, MARKET CONDITIONS, MARKET DEMAND, MARKET ENVIRONMENT, MARKET FAILURE, MARKET INSTABILITY, MARKET PARTICIPANTS, MARKET PRICE, MARKET PRICES, MARKET REGULATION, MARKET STABILIZATION, MARKET STOCKS, MARKET VOLATILITY, MARKETING, MARKETING BOARDS, MATURITIES, MONOPOLIES, MONOPOLY, OIL PRICE, OIL PRICES, OPTIMIZATION, OPTIONS MARKETS, OUTPUT, PETROLEUM PRICES, POLICY RESPONSES, PORTFOLIO, PORTFOLIO ALLOCATION, PRICE BAND, PRICE BEHAVIOR, PRICE CEILING, PRICE CHANGES, PRICE EFFECT, PRICE FLOOR, PRICE FLUCTUATIONS, PRICE INCREASE, PRICE INCREASES, PRICE INDEX, PRICE INDEXES, PRICE MOVEMENTS, PRICE RISK, PRICE SERIES, PRICE STABILIZATION, PRICE SUPPORT, PRICE TRENDS, PRICE VOLATILITY, PRIVATE MARKET, PRODUCTION COSTS, PRODUCTION EFFICIENCY, PUBLIC BUDGETS, PUBLIC SALES, PUBLIC STOCK, PUBLIC STOCKS, RANDOM WALK, RESERVE, RETURNS, RISK­NEUTRAL, SALE, SALES, SMOOTHING CONSUMPTION, SPOT MARKET, SPOT PRICES, STOCK ADJUSTMENTS, STOCK DATA, STOCKS, STORAGE CAPACITY, SUBSTITUTE, SUBSTITUTION, SUPPLIER, SUPPLIERS, SUPPLY SHOCK, SUPPLY SHOCKS, SURPLUSES, TAX, TAX POLICIES, TRADE BARRIERS, TRADE POLICY, TRADING, TRADING VOLUME, TRANSACTION, TRANSACTION COSTS, TRANSPARENCY, VOLATILITY, WEALTH, WORLD MARKETS, WORLD TRADE, WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION, WTO,
Online Access:http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/main?menuPK=64187510&pagePK=64193027&piPK=64187937&theSitePK=523679&menuPK=64187510&searchMenuPK=64187283&siteName=WDS&entityID=000158349_20090825154655
https://hdl.handle.net/10986/4220
Tags: Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
Description
Summary:In the long view, recent grain price volatility is not anomalous. Wheat, rice, and maize are highly substitutable in the global market for calories, and when aggregate stocks decline to minimal feasible levels, prices become highly sensitive to small shocks, consistent with storage models. In this decade, stocks have declined due to high income growth and biofuels mandates. Recently, shocks including the Australian drought and biofuels demand boosts due to the oil price spike were exacerbated by a sequence of trade restrictions by key exporters beginning in the thin global rice market in the fall of 2007, which turned market anxiety into panic. To protect vulnerable consumers, countries intervened in storage markets and, if they were exporters, to limit trade access. Recognizing these realities, vulnerable countries are building strategic reserves. The associated expense and negative incentive effects can be controlled if reserves have quantitative targets related to the consumption needs of the most vulnerable, with distribution to the latter only in severe emergencies. More-ambitious plans manipulate world prices via buffer stocks or naked short speculation to keep prices consistent with fundamentals. Past interventions of either kind have been expensive, ineffective, and generally short-lived. Further, there is no significant evidence that prices do not reflect fundamentals, including export market access.