Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform

The objective of this good practice note is to outline the ingredients of an assessment of the fiscal impacts of energy subsidies in an economy from the aggregate fiscal perspective of the government. It demonstrates the interrelations between the fiscal balance, its financing, and impact on key debt and fiscal sustainability indicators. As discussed in the Energy Sector Reform Assessment Framework (ESRAF) Good Practice Note on the definition of energy subsidies (Good Practice Note 1), energy subsidies may be provided through various channels on the production and consumption sides, and may generate contingent liabilities—explicit or implicit—for a government that must be monitored and managed as part of overall macroeconomic management. ESRAF defines an energy subsidy as a deliberate policy action by the government that specifically targets electricity, fuels, or district heating and that reduces the net cost of energy purchased, reduces the cost of energy production or delivery, increases the revenues retained by energy suppliers, or has any combination of these three effects. ESRAF also covers non-energy use of oil, gas, and coal, such as natural gas used as a feed stock for fertilizer manufacture and naphtha and liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) used as feed stocks in petrochemicals. Subsidies are not always paid for by the government. Consumers may subsidize producers, producers may subsidize consumers, and financiers and other actors not linked to energy consumption or production, including those outside the country, may be covering the costs of subsidies. This note focuses on the costs of subsidies to the government. One important form of subsidies consists of direct budgetary transfers from the government to either consumers or producers, which are recorded in the government public sector budget. For instance, with the justification of social benefits, governments often establish consumer prices for energy that are below reference prices (prices that would have prevailed in a competitive market, or the cost of efficient production if a competitive market does not exist), and then compensate the energy suppliers for the difference (also referred to as the price gap) between the reference prices and the government controlled prices.' Another subsidy delivery mechanism is provision of the subsidy benefits directly to end users, typically households. In addition, a government may provide subsidies in the form of tax exemptions to energy service providers, tax credits for investment, or allowing the energy-related public utilities and national oil companies to run arrears on their debt service and other payment obligations to the government.

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Main Author: Goopu, Sudarshan
Format: Report biblioteca
Language:English
Published: World Bank, Washington, DC 2018-06-30
Subjects:FISCAL RISK, ENERGY SUBSIDIES, STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES, PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS, PUBLIC SECTOR MANAGEMENT, ENERGY PRICES,
Online Access:http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/958771530881102150/Assessing-the-Fiscal-Cost-of-Subsidies-and-Fiscal-Impact-of-Reform-Energy-Subsidy-Reform-Assessment-Framework-ESRAF-Good-Practice-Note-2
http://hdl.handle.net/10986/30253
Tags: Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
id dig-okr-1098630253
record_format koha
spelling dig-okr-10986302532021-09-16T11:16:05Z Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform Goopu, Sudarshan FISCAL RISK ENERGY SUBSIDIES STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS PUBLIC SECTOR MANAGEMENT ENERGY PRICES The objective of this good practice note is to outline the ingredients of an assessment of the fiscal impacts of energy subsidies in an economy from the aggregate fiscal perspective of the government. It demonstrates the interrelations between the fiscal balance, its financing, and impact on key debt and fiscal sustainability indicators. As discussed in the Energy Sector Reform Assessment Framework (ESRAF) Good Practice Note on the definition of energy subsidies (Good Practice Note 1), energy subsidies may be provided through various channels on the production and consumption sides, and may generate contingent liabilities—explicit or implicit—for a government that must be monitored and managed as part of overall macroeconomic management. ESRAF defines an energy subsidy as a deliberate policy action by the government that specifically targets electricity, fuels, or district heating and that reduces the net cost of energy purchased, reduces the cost of energy production or delivery, increases the revenues retained by energy suppliers, or has any combination of these three effects. ESRAF also covers non-energy use of oil, gas, and coal, such as natural gas used as a feed stock for fertilizer manufacture and naphtha and liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) used as feed stocks in petrochemicals. Subsidies are not always paid for by the government. Consumers may subsidize producers, producers may subsidize consumers, and financiers and other actors not linked to energy consumption or production, including those outside the country, may be covering the costs of subsidies. This note focuses on the costs of subsidies to the government. One important form of subsidies consists of direct budgetary transfers from the government to either consumers or producers, which are recorded in the government public sector budget. For instance, with the justification of social benefits, governments often establish consumer prices for energy that are below reference prices (prices that would have prevailed in a competitive market, or the cost of efficient production if a competitive market does not exist), and then compensate the energy suppliers for the difference (also referred to as the price gap) between the reference prices and the government controlled prices.' Another subsidy delivery mechanism is provision of the subsidy benefits directly to end users, typically households. In addition, a government may provide subsidies in the form of tax exemptions to energy service providers, tax credits for investment, or allowing the energy-related public utilities and national oil companies to run arrears on their debt service and other payment obligations to the government. 2018-08-20T16:08:06Z 2018-08-20T16:08:06Z 2018-06-30 Report http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/958771530881102150/Assessing-the-Fiscal-Cost-of-Subsidies-and-Fiscal-Impact-of-Reform-Energy-Subsidy-Reform-Assessment-Framework-ESRAF-Good-Practice-Note-2 http://hdl.handle.net/10986/30253 English CC BY 3.0 IGO http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/igo World Bank World Bank, Washington, DC Publications & Research :: ESMAP Paper Publications & Research
institution Banco Mundial
collection DSpace
country Estados Unidos
countrycode US
component Bibliográfico
access En linea
databasecode dig-okr
tag biblioteca
region America del Norte
libraryname Biblioteca del Banco Mundial
language English
topic FISCAL RISK
ENERGY SUBSIDIES
STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES
PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS
PUBLIC SECTOR MANAGEMENT
ENERGY PRICES
FISCAL RISK
ENERGY SUBSIDIES
STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES
PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS
PUBLIC SECTOR MANAGEMENT
ENERGY PRICES
spellingShingle FISCAL RISK
ENERGY SUBSIDIES
STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES
PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS
PUBLIC SECTOR MANAGEMENT
ENERGY PRICES
FISCAL RISK
ENERGY SUBSIDIES
STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES
PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS
PUBLIC SECTOR MANAGEMENT
ENERGY PRICES
Goopu, Sudarshan
Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform
description The objective of this good practice note is to outline the ingredients of an assessment of the fiscal impacts of energy subsidies in an economy from the aggregate fiscal perspective of the government. It demonstrates the interrelations between the fiscal balance, its financing, and impact on key debt and fiscal sustainability indicators. As discussed in the Energy Sector Reform Assessment Framework (ESRAF) Good Practice Note on the definition of energy subsidies (Good Practice Note 1), energy subsidies may be provided through various channels on the production and consumption sides, and may generate contingent liabilities—explicit or implicit—for a government that must be monitored and managed as part of overall macroeconomic management. ESRAF defines an energy subsidy as a deliberate policy action by the government that specifically targets electricity, fuels, or district heating and that reduces the net cost of energy purchased, reduces the cost of energy production or delivery, increases the revenues retained by energy suppliers, or has any combination of these three effects. ESRAF also covers non-energy use of oil, gas, and coal, such as natural gas used as a feed stock for fertilizer manufacture and naphtha and liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) used as feed stocks in petrochemicals. Subsidies are not always paid for by the government. Consumers may subsidize producers, producers may subsidize consumers, and financiers and other actors not linked to energy consumption or production, including those outside the country, may be covering the costs of subsidies. This note focuses on the costs of subsidies to the government. One important form of subsidies consists of direct budgetary transfers from the government to either consumers or producers, which are recorded in the government public sector budget. For instance, with the justification of social benefits, governments often establish consumer prices for energy that are below reference prices (prices that would have prevailed in a competitive market, or the cost of efficient production if a competitive market does not exist), and then compensate the energy suppliers for the difference (also referred to as the price gap) between the reference prices and the government controlled prices.' Another subsidy delivery mechanism is provision of the subsidy benefits directly to end users, typically households. In addition, a government may provide subsidies in the form of tax exemptions to energy service providers, tax credits for investment, or allowing the energy-related public utilities and national oil companies to run arrears on their debt service and other payment obligations to the government.
format Report
topic_facet FISCAL RISK
ENERGY SUBSIDIES
STATE-OWNED ENTERPRISES
PUBLIC-PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS
PUBLIC SECTOR MANAGEMENT
ENERGY PRICES
author Goopu, Sudarshan
author_facet Goopu, Sudarshan
author_sort Goopu, Sudarshan
title Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform
title_short Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform
title_full Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform
title_fullStr Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform
title_full_unstemmed Energy Subsidy Reform Assessment Framework : Assessing the Fiscal Cost of Subsidies and Fiscal Impact of Reform
title_sort energy subsidy reform assessment framework : assessing the fiscal cost of subsidies and fiscal impact of reform
publisher World Bank, Washington, DC
publishDate 2018-06-30
url http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/958771530881102150/Assessing-the-Fiscal-Cost-of-Subsidies-and-Fiscal-Impact-of-Reform-Energy-Subsidy-Reform-Assessment-Framework-ESRAF-Good-Practice-Note-2
http://hdl.handle.net/10986/30253
work_keys_str_mv AT goopusudarshan energysubsidyreformassessmentframeworkassessingthefiscalcostofsubsidiesandfiscalimpactofreform
_version_ 1756575169334214656